Zap! You’re frozen! has never worked. Why is Trudeau floating price controls now?

Vincent GelosoIf we could tame inflation with laws and regulations, we would have discovered it by now.

But that’s not stopping Prime Minister Justin Trudeau from letting it be understood that he’s getting ready to try once again where so many others have failed before him. In the last few weeks, his government studied, amongst other things, France’s approach, namely freezing grocery store food prices.

There’s nothing new or original about the idea of a price freeze. The first documented historical case goes all the way back to the Roman emperor Diocletian in the year 301. The literature tells us that it didn’t work back in the day, and it hasn’t worked any better in the intervening centuries. In fact, in economics, the measure is widely seen as being counterproductive.

price controls inflation trudeau
Related Stories
Trudeau must drop his grocery tax threat


Shrinkflation warning labels on food coming to Canada?


Dollarama a lifeline for Canadians struggling to make ends meet


What needs to be understood is that a price acts a bit like a thermometer. Simply put, it acts as an indicator of the level at which the amount producers are ready to supply to the market is equivalent to the quantity demanded by consumers based on what they have to spend.

Inflation, in this analogy, is the equivalent of a temperature increase. Instead of it being 24 degrees in your home, it is now 28. The idea of a price control amounts to exchanging the thermometer for a smaller one that only goes up to 24, then declaring that the problem is solved. Clearly, this strategy does not actually solve the problem but rather deprives us of information regarding its extent and its evolution.

Just as the best way to lower the temperature in your home is to adjust the thermostat, taming inflation happens through the monetary policies of central banks.

Just because the government imposes price controls and observed prices stop rising doesn’t mean that the actual value or real prices cease to increase.

For example, companies subject to government price controls frequently adjust the product size – so-called “shrinkflation.”

An example commonly used is that of former U.S. President Richard Nixon, who, in the 1970s, decreed price controls over building materials. To respect the regulated price, while still reacting to increases in production costs, manufacturers modified the dimensions of boards. While the posted price remained the same, the real price continued to go up.

Another telling example is that of the rationing that was imposed during the Second World War. Ottawa imposed price controls on a vast array of goods and services. However, this led to shortages. It, therefore, became necessary to ration products. At the time, Canadians had to stand in long lines to purchase the goods they needed, and even then could only do so in limited quantities.

The result was the creation of illicit markets – with much higher prices than the official prices – allowing consumers to buy the products they needed in greater quantities than what was authorized by the rationing system. To top it all off, merchants used to sell their lower quality goods in the market controlled by the government and keep their better quality goods for the black market.

Whatever we might think of price controls, they impose very real costs on individuals. They’re just harder to see. Fellow economist Casey Pender and I estimated prudently that real inflation in Canada at the time was 48 percent – well above the official figure of 28 percent reported back then. A similar exercise leads to a similar observation in the United States.

We could continue citing example after example, but we would quickly exceed the allotted word limit for this piece.

The fact is that regulating prices does not solve the fundamental problem of inflation. It does not interrupt the “price spiral.” On the contrary, it merely reduces the quality of economic information available to consumers, entrepreneurs, and policy-makers.

To fight inflation, the central bank needs to adopt a sound monetary policy, and economic growth needs to be encouraged. These might not be easy solutions, but they at least have the virtue of actually working.

Vincent Geloso is an Assistant Professor of Economics at George Mason University and Senior Economist at the Montreal Economic Institute.

For interview requests, click here.


The opinions expressed by our columnists and contributors are theirs alone and do not inherently or expressly reflect the views of our publication.

© Troy Media
Troy Media is an editorial content provider to media outlets and its own hosted community news outlets across Canada.